Where to begin?
Let’s look at some data. The figures below are from
“Where A is Ordinary: The Evolution of American College and University Grading,
1940-2009” (Rojstaczer and Healy, Teacher’s
College Record, 2012, 114, 070306). The dataset is large and
comprises a variety of institutional types, both private and public, and also
by region.
The most dramatic trends are the increase of A’s and
the decrease of C’s. There’s a dip in D’s but smaller. B’s hover between 35-40%
and F’s hold steady at 5%. C was the most common grade circa 1940 but was
supplanted by B starting in 1965. In 1997, A became the most common grade and
its rise continues. (The small “bump” in A’s in the early ‘70s is partly
attributed to instructor attitudes during the Vietnam war.) There are
differences in the fine-grained data. Schools in the South tend to give lower
grades. Public schools show less inflation than privates. Some specific schools
(Central Michigan, Colorado, Princeton) had specific policies to combat grade
inflation. The private-public difference is the starkest as seen from data
comparing 1960, 1980, and 2007.
Why are grades rising?
Some schools argue that they are getting academically stronger students. Perhaps they are, at least based on increases in
average SAT/ACT scores of incoming students. However, this increase is small
percentage-wise compared to the increase in grades. Some argue that more women
attending college have moved grades up. (It is well documented that on average women
perform better GPA-wise.) However, comparing both the period and the rate of
increase in percentage of college-attending women once again does not match up
with observed grade inflation. Perhaps teaching methods are improving. But there’s
little data to suggest any effect even if the statement is (partially) true. Perhaps
students are choosing “easier” majors. Perhaps the rise in adjunct faculty with
precarious job security. Perhaps the changing attitude of higher education
towards student-as-customer.
These and other scenarios are discussed by Rojstaczer
and Healy with no firm answer to the why question, although they seem to favor
the last “perhaps” in the paragraph above when writing their conclusion: “Our
data suggest that in the absence of oversight from leadership concerned about
grade inflation, grades will almost always rise in an academic environment
where professors sense that there are incentives to please students… the
principle incentives likely have been a mix of the ability to enhance students’
postgraduate prospects, and with the rise of importance of student-based
evaluations, faculty self interest.”
The problem stated by the article title remains.
Once an A becomes ordinary, it loses value as a signaling factor to employers,
post-graduate programs, and any other entity using grades as some sort of
benchmark. It is not surprising to see the rise of alternate credentialism. Rojstaczer and Healy exhort universities to rein in “grades that bear
little relation to actual performance”. This will not be easy, because of
larger systemic issues. The issue is complicated, although economists
(particularly game theorists) are attempting to model “what if” scenarios to
get at the problem. The remainder of today’s blog post will highlight just a
few examples. Note that unlike the data-driven model for grade norming previously discussed, most game-theory studies come with necessarily
simplified assumptions without a supporting data set. I won’t go into the
game-theory models, but I will cite the papers for the math-inclined who’d want
to read propositions, proofs, and lemmas.
In “A Signaling Theory of Grade Inflation” by Chan
et al. (International Economic Review,
2007, 48, 1065-1090), their game-theory model suggests that when one
school inflates grades, other schools will follow suit. Here’s the crux: “When
a school gives a lot of good grades, the labor market cannot fully distinguish
whether this is due to an overly liberal grading standard or whether the school
is blessed with a large proportion of high-ability students.” On the one hand,
schools trying to help their students get jobs have an incentive to raise grades.
On the other hand, a school’s top students might be less distinguishable from
their peers. Employers have some knowledge of a student’s abilities, but less than
the school that’s (purposely/strategically) providing coarse-grained signaling.
Essentially, “grade inflation reduces the
information content of grades and thus impedes optimal task assignment by
employers”. To hedge their bets, employers might choose to hire higher GPA
students from colleges that have higher average GPAs because there’s a decent
probability of getting a high-ability student. Elite colleges are incentivized to
continue grade inflation to keep more of their students in these “virtuous
cycles”, and thus the hamster wheels turn. After all, brand-name is a signaling
factor. Those of us in academia know this well, unfortunately. Academic
snobbery is rife. I’m sure I benefited, at least getting my foot in the door
where job offers were concerned. But grade inflation isn’t purely an academia
issue; similar phenomena show up in consumer magazines, accounting audits of
companies, stock-picking in investment banking, and more. Hence, the interest
of economists, I guess.
Schools that perpetrate more grade inflation,
might, they just might, have better quality education – at least judged by increased
resources funneled into education. That’s the argument by Boleslavsky and
Cotton in “Grading Standards and Education Quality” (American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2005, 7, 248-279). The
situation faced by employers (or evaluators): “transcripts are less
informative, hindering the ex post selection of high-ability graduates, but
schools invest more in education quality, so graduates are more likely to be
high ability ex ante.” The authors’ model finds that this “effect on investment
may dominate” setting up a complementarity between school and employer. A look
at the U.S. landscape certainly bears this out when considering the brand-name
schools with large endowments and operating expenses. A virtuous upward spiral
perhaps.
The final article I highlight today is “Student
sorting and implications for grade inflation” by Herron and Markovich (Rationality and Society, 2017, 29, 355-386). In their model, departments (majors) are divided into
two types: ability-revealing or ability concealing. Their conclusion:
grade inflation is (at least partly) driven by how students sort themselves
into departments. This grade-related sorting was mentioned in my previous post
as to why grade norming might bring more women into STEM. The authors
sound a cautionary note to a hypothetical university dean who sees many A’s in
a department. In an ability-concealing department, grades aren’t distinguishing
the stronger students from the less academically-inclined. In an
ability-revealing department, avoided by weaker students, the high grades might
be an accurate reflection of student caliber. Thus, the claim “our students are
excellent!” might be true and reasonable. How might one tell the difference?
The authors suggest indirect measures (because there are confounding variables);
I encourage you to read the article for details. There is evidence that
introductory course grades in ability-revealing departments (where you see the
full distribution of grades including many low ones) are better predictors of
future student performance comparted to ability-concealing departments.
There are several interesting offshoots mentioned
at the end of the article. The authors make an argument that the emergence of
ability-concealing departments in a university, even just one or two, could
over time lead to the present situation because of the way students sort
themselves based on their own perceived abilities. Weaker students move towards
ability-concealing departments, while stronger students, to distinguish
themselves, migrate to ability-revealing departments. The (idealized) model
assumes students know their own ability and can perfectly rank themselves
within their cohort. This, we all know as educators, is not true – thus the actual
situation is much messier. The authors write: “This sort of error is
particularly pernicious for students because a high-ability student who
believes that she is of low ability may prefer an ability-concealing department
over an ability-revealing department – even though the latter would be more
valuable.” Risk-aversion is complicated, although studies do show that on
average women are more risk averse than men, at least where grades are
concerned.
What to do?
I close by quoting the authors on the challenges of
a department trying to mitigate grade inflation. “A department that by itself
wanted to address institution-wide grade inflation can be stymied by the
ability-concealing behaviors of other departments. If an ability-revealing
department were to make its classes increasingly challenging in an attempt to
mitigate inflation, then it would make the overall grade inflation problem
worse and in so doing decrease its own enrollments. To the extent that low
enrollments are problematic for departments are problematic for departments who
might want to use enrollment figures to argue for faculty positions, no
department has an incentive on its own to increase the cost associated with its
classes. This sort of collective action dilemma means that university
administrators should not assume that individual departments will ever be able
to coordinate themselves and form a solution to what administrators might
consider a grade inflation problem.”
No comments:
Post a Comment